Restricting promotions of food and drink high in fat, sugar or salt: business and regulatory impact assessment - partial
Partial business and regulatory impact assessment of proposals to restrict promotions of food and drink high in fat sugar or salt (HFSS).
4. Options
Options Developed
To develop the options under consideration, we characterise the policy along three dimensions:
- What food products
- What forms of promotion
- Places that would be subject to restrictions.
The four options under consideration are summarised below. In all options, we envisage the following sectors being directly affected: retailers, out of home, manufacturers, and local government through enforcement costs.
Option 1 – do nothing
In this scenario, there are no new regulations on the promotion of HFSS foods which would be brought into force. We therefore assume no impact on current population weight trajectories. The current costs of overweight and obesity are therefore borne for the duration of the modelled period.
We compare all other options to this option – i.e. the results of the costs and benefits of the other options are the difference between that option and the ‘do nothing’ baseline. Over the modelling horizon, government could choose to pursue other policies that complement or mediate the effects of policies considered here. Industry may also implement restrictions voluntarily in the absence of regulations, particularly if there are restrictions in place in other areas of the UK and businesses operating across the UK align their promotional activity and practices. We do not attempt to quantify these impacts.
Option 2 – Price (volume, e.g. multi-buy) and location restrictions for discretionary foods and ice cream and dairy desserts, no exemptions
Products where the restrictions apply will be defined by:
- Checking if a product matches the Food Standards Scotland definition[25] of a discretionary food
- Then applying a Nutrient Profile Model
- Products that are discretionary AND fail the NPM would be in scope for the proposed restrictions.
The restrictions would apply to: retailers and the out of home sector (which includes cafes, restaurants, bars etc.). There would be no exemptions based on size of business.
In this option, we consider the restriction of location promotions and also volume price promotions “i.e. multi-buy”. "Multi-buys" are defined here as (a) two or more separate products sold together to obtain a discount or (b) one or more products given free as a result of a purchase[26].The restriction of wider price promotions (i.e. Temporary Price Reductions, meal deals etc) is not included.
Option 3 (a, b, c) – price (volume, e.g. multi-buy excluding meal deals and TPRs) and location promotion restrictions for discretionary foods and ice cream and dairy desserts and additional foods, exemptions for micro and small businesses for all restrictions or location restrictions, considered alongside no exemptions.
Option 3(a) This option uses the same set of restrictions as Option 2, but expands the targeted food products beyond the discretionary classification to include categories of most concern to childhood obesity which also fail an NPM test. (This would be broadly in line with the regulations in England.)
Additionally we consider the effects of exempting micro and small businesses from all the restrictions (Option 3(b)), and also from exempting them only from the location restrictions (Option 3(c)). Micro and Small businesses are defined as those employing fewer than 50 people at the enterprise level.
Option 4 (a, b and c) – price (all price promotions – volume, e.g. multi-buy including meal deals and Temporary Price Reductions) and location promotion restrictions for discretionary and ice cream and dairy desserts and additional foods, exemptions for micro and small businesses for all restrictions or location restrictions only, considered alongside no exemptions.
The set of products within scope is the same as in Option 3(a), however restrictions are expanded to include all price promotions beyond volume multi-buy offers including meal deals and Temporary Price Reductions.
Exemptions for micro and small businesses for all restrictions (Option 4(c)), or location restrictions only (Option 4(b)), are considered alongside no exemptions for any promotion (Option 4(a)).
Sectors and Groups Affected
To understand the impact of the policy propositions on the economy, we develop different calculations for each sector affected. To define the impacts on private sector businesses, we make use of the Scottish Business Survey and Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes at the 5-digit level. This section presents background data for the sectoral impacts presented in section 12. The primary impacts of the policy proposals are on subsets of the following sectors: Retailers (SIC 47); the Out of Home sector (SIC 56); and Manufacturers (SIC 10).
We also include the impacts on health (direct health benefits to individuals, impacts on NHS and Social Care costs); and government (costs of enforcement).
The following sections outline the scope of the sectors affected. Throughout, we make reference to enterprise and unit level. Enterprises are the number of businesses operating in a sector, and units are the number of premises operated by enterprises, i.e. individual stores.
Retail Sector
We assume that the following retailer enterprise types will fall within the scope of the restrictions, based on their Standard Industry Classification 5-digit code – Table 1. We assume that other than exemptions by size, the same businesses would be in scope irrespective of the products targeted or types of restrictions imposed.
Table 1: Retailers within scope of restrictions by 5 digit SIC code
Food and Drink Retail
47110 : Retail sale in non-specialised stores with food, beverages or tobacco predominating
47210 : Retail sale of fruit and vegetables in specialised stores
47220 : Retail sale of meat and meat products in specialised stores
47230 : Retail sale of fish, crustaceans and molluscs in specialised stores
47240 : Retail sale of bread, cakes, flour confectionery and sugar confectionery in specialised stores
47250 : Retail sale of beverages in specialised stores
47290 : Other retail sale of food in specialised stores
47810 : Retail sale via stalls and markets of food, beverages and tobacco products
Non-food retailers
47190 : Other retail sale in non-specialised stores
47300 : Retail sale of automotive fuel in specialised stores
47620 : Retail sale of newspapers and stationery in specialised stores
Table 2 summarises the number of enterprises, by number of employees, from the Inter Departmental Business Register[27] in these categories. Based on this we estimate that 5,670 Scottish retail sector businesses will be affected by this policy. There are 4,730 food-related enterprises and 940 non-food enterprises that will also be in-scope due to selling low volume of food items as part of their business. It should be noted that each business which operates under a franchise agreement as part of symbol group would still count as an individual businesses in these statistics.
Description |
Business Size |
Total Businesses |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Food and Drink Retail |
4,195 |
475 |
35 |
25 |
4,730 |
Non-food retailers |
790 |
100 |
15 |
30 |
940 |
Retailers total |
4,985 |
575 |
50 |
55 |
5,670 |
The costs to businesses of these restrictions will fall at both the enterprise level (the business) and the unit level (individual stores). Table 3 presents the number of units in scope for the policy based on the number of employees at each local unit. 9,310 local units are expected to be in scope for this policy. There are 7,230 food-related units, and 2,080 non-food units in scope.
Description |
Number of business sites in Scotland (split by number of employees at business site) |
Total number of business sites |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Food and Drink Retail |
5,085 |
1,820 |
255 |
70 |
7,230 |
Non-food retailers |
1,350 |
655 |
65 |
5 |
2,080 |
Retailers total |
6,435 |
2,475 |
320 |
75 |
9,310 |
The number of units for businesses of different sizes is presented in Table 4. This highlights that while there are only a small number of large businesses, those large businesses have a significant number of different units (i.e. individual stores) across their business. This is important when considering potential exemptions from restrictions if these are applied at the enterprise level rather than individual unit level.
Description |
Number of business sites in Scotland (split by number of employees in businesses in UK) |
Total number of business sites |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Food and Drink Retail |
4,230 |
655 |
240 |
2,110 |
7,230 |
Non-food retailers |
800 |
145 |
80 |
1,050 |
2,080 |
Retailers total |
5,030 |
800 |
320 |
3,160 |
9,310 |
Take home grocery sales
The proposed policy measures will have an impact on retailers’ sales and therefore profits. To calculate these impacts, we use data from Kantar that estimated the total value of take-home grocery purchases in Scotland at £10.5 billion in 2022[28].
Products in-scope for the proposed policy differ across the options. Option 2 includes discretionary foods and ice cream and dairy desserts (Option 2 in the public consultation), while options 3 and 4 include categories that are of most concern to childhood obesity, which is discretionary foods, ice cream and dairy desserts, breakfast cereals, sweetened yoghurt and fromage frais, pizza, ready meals, and roast potatoes, chips and similar potato products (Option 3 in the public consultation).
Analysis provided by FSS shows that, by value, discretionary products and ice cream and dairy desserts make up 21.2% of Scottish consumers’ purchases, and including additional products in scope brings the total share of spending to 29.8%[29].
Category |
Proportion of total grocery spend (%) |
---|---|
Sweet biscuits* |
2.2 |
Total confectionery* |
4.8 |
Cakes and pastries + higher fat/sugar morning goods* |
3 |
Crisps and savoury snacks* |
2.9 |
Puddings and desserts* |
1.2 |
Ice cream and edible ices (excl. frozen dairy desserts)* |
1.1 |
Regular soft drinks (excl. water)* |
6 |
Discretionary and ice cream and dairy desserts sub-total |
21.2 |
Breakfast cereals |
1.4 |
Total ready meals |
3.6 |
Yoghurt and fromage frais |
1.5 |
Pizza |
1.2 |
Roast and processed potatoes |
0.9 |
Additional products sub-total |
8.6 |
Total |
29.8 |
Table 5 summarises this by food category, where categories annotated with an * are classed as discretionary products and ice cream and dairy desserts.
Out of Home Sector
The policy proposals apply to food sold in the course of a business. This includes the out-of-home sector (OoH). Following the approach to retailers, we summarise these businesses using the Standard Industry Classification system ONS codes, used to classify business establishments by the type of economic activity in which they’re engaged. Table 6 shows the businesses we assume are in scope of the policy (irrespective of foods or restrictions in scope).
Table 6: OoH within scope of restrictions by 5 digit SIC code
Accommodation
55100 : Hotels and similar accommodation
Food and drink services
56102 : Unlicensed restaurants and cafes
56103 : Take away food shops and mobile food stands
56210 : Event catering activities
56290 : Other food service activities
56302 : Public houses and bars
56101 : Licensed restaurants
There are 13,120 OoH enterprises in scope in the sector, maintaining 15,990 units. The set of enterprises (Table 7) and units (Table 8), by employment in UK in enterprise and individual unit respectively are presented below.
Description |
Business size |
Total businesses |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Accommodation |
845 |
615 |
135 |
45 |
1,645 |
Food and drink services |
9,030 |
2,240 |
115 |
90 |
11,475 |
Out-of-Home total |
9,875 |
2,855 |
250 |
135 |
13,120 |
Description |
Number of business sites in Scotland (split by number of employees at business site) |
Total number of business sites |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Accommodation |
885 |
900 |
185 |
5 |
1,980 |
Food and drink services |
10,135 |
3,620 |
245 |
5 |
14,010 |
Out-of-Home total |
11,020 |
4,520 |
430 |
10 |
15,990 |
As with retailers, the number of local units for different size enterprises (employees across UK) is shown in Table 9.
Description |
Number of business sites in Scotland (split by number of employees in businesses in UK) |
Total number of business sites |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Accommodation |
850 |
650 |
205 |
275 |
1,980 |
Food and drink services |
9,045 |
2,490 |
365 |
2,105 |
14,010 |
Out-of-Home total |
9,895 |
3,140 |
570 |
2,380 |
15,990 |
Manufacturers
We also model the impact of the policy on manufacturers in Scotland. We anticipate that the proposed restrictions will lead to a net reduction in sales of food, with the fall in sales of restricted foods being larger than the compensatory increase in sales of non-HFSS foods. This reduction will feed back to manufacturers.
There is limited evidence of the impact of the UK Government restrictions on location promotions of HFSS foods in England given the relatively short time since their introduction in October 2022. However, early descriptive analysis from Kantar following the first six months of restrictions being in place in England noted apparent changes in consumer behaviour in the categories impacted by the legislation. For instance, in the 12 weeks to 19 March 2023, they observed a movement of £82 million away from HFSS products within the legislation categories, with £34.4 million of this moving to healthier non-HFSS alternatives. However, no assessment was provided on the impact on total food and drink expenditure.[30]
Again following the structure above, we use Standard Industry Classification codes to define the manufacturers in scope that are likely to be most affected by the policy proposals.
Industry |
Total |
Micro (0 - 9) |
Small (10 - 49) |
Medium (50 - 249) |
Large (250+) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
10520 : Manufacture of ice cream |
30 |
15 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
10821 : Manufacture of cocoa, and chocolate confectionery |
30 |
20 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
10822 : Manufacture of sugar confectionery |
20 |
5 |
10 |
5 |
0 |
10310 : Processing and preserving of potatoes |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10612 : Manufacture of breakfast cereals and cereals-based foods |
5 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10720 : Manufacture of rusks and biscuits; manufacture of preserved pastry goods and cakes |
35 |
20 |
10 |
10 |
0 |
10850 : Manufacture of prepared meals and dishes |
25 |
20 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
10519 : Manufacture of milk products (other than liquid milk and cream, butter, cheese) |
10 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10710 : Manufacture of bread; manufacture of fresh pastry goods and cakes |
260 |
170 |
70 |
15 |
5 |
11070 : Manufacture of soft drinks; production of mineral waters and other bottled waters |
30 |
25 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
Manufacturers in scope |
450 |
290 |
120 |
30 |
5 |
Local government
To enforce the policy, there are direct costs to Scotland’s 32 local authorities in terms of familiarising their staff with regulations, and in terms of using time during visits to businesses to establish whether regulations are being followed. To help inform estimates and costing implications for local authorities we have been working with the Financial and Delivery Considerations Group to facilitate engagement between Scottish Government, Food Standards Scotland, local government and enforcement professionals to support effective enforcement of the policy.
Health
The policy is intended to reduce the number of calories consumed via HFSS products, as well as shifting the nutritional content of diets towards healthier products.
This will have direct health benefits to individuals, and reduce spending in the NHS and Social Care sectors by reducing the likelihood of individuals developing obesity and other diet-related health conditions. While the transition costs to businesses and the expected reduction in sales of HFSS foods as a result of restricting promotions will be immediate, the health benefits from reduced calorie intake and improved nutritional intake will take longer to feed through into reduced disease prevalence, and therefore the economic and social benefits associated with the policy. As such, the costs and benefits are considered over a 25 year policy period to allow time for the beneficial impacts to materialise. The further into the future a benefit arises the less weight it carries in the overall estimation of the Net Present Value due to the discounting of costs and benefits by 3.5% each year into the future.
There will also be an improvement in economic productivity due to reduced absence, arising from these health improvements.
Affected Employees
We make a number of assumptions about how businesses will respond to the policies. In particular we estimate the one-off costs transition costs of familiarisation and implementation by using illustrative costs of different workers’ time. We use data from Annual Survey of Hours and Earnings[32], taking the average (mean) 2022 wage cost to estimate the resource costs after the addition of non-labour employment costs (assumed as a 30% increase over wage costs). The job definitions, and hourly wages, are summarised in Table 11.
Year |
Region |
Description |
Code |
Median pay |
Mean pay |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
2022 |
UK |
Shopkeepers and proprietors – wholesale and retail |
7131 |
12.68 |
16.77 |
2022 |
UK |
Managers and directors in retail and wholesale |
1150 |
14.58 |
18.17 |
2022 |
UK |
Sales assistants and retail cashiers |
711 |
10.15 |
11.23 |
2022 |
UK |
Purchasing managers and directors |
1134 |
24.85 |
26.53 |
2022 |
UK |
Programmers and software development professionals |
2134 |
23.51 |
24.99 |
2022 |
UK |
Stock control clerks and assistants |
4133 |
12.16 |
13.39 |
2022 |
UK |
Restaurant and catering establishment managers and proprietors |
1222 |
12.51 |
13.78 |
2022 |
UK |
Catering and bar managers |
5436 |
11.64 |
12.62 |
2022 |
UK |
Food preparation and hospitality trades |
543 |
11 |
11.81 |
Uprated wage to account for non-wage labour costs |
Adjustment |
Median pay |
Mean pay |
||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
2022 |
UK |
Shopkeepers and proprietors – wholesale and retail |
30% |
16.48 |
21.80 |
2022 |
UK |
Managers and directors in retail and wholesale |
30% |
18.95 |
23.62 |
2022 |
UK |
Sales assistants and retail cashiers |
30% |
13.20 |
14.60 |
2022 |
UK |
Purchasing managers and directors |
30% |
32.31 |
34.49 |
2022 |
UK |
Programmers and software development professionals |
30% |
30.56 |
32.49 |
2022 |
UK |
Stock control clerks and assistants |
30% |
15.81 |
17.41 |
2022 |
UK |
Restaurant and catering establishment managers and proprietors |
30% |
16.26 |
17.91 |
2022 |
UK |
Catering and bar managers |
30% |
15.13 |
16.41 |
2022 |
UK |
Food preparation and hospitality trades |
30% |
14.30 |
15.35 |
Exemptions by business size
A number of the options consider the impact of the policies if micro and small businesses were exempt from location and/or price promotion restrictions. To consider the potential impact on sales we exclude the share of sales (revenue) which come from micro and small businesses from the expenditure from both retail and Out of Home calculations. The revenue in the sectors by business size is shown in Table 12.
Description |
£m Turnover by employee sizeband (split by number of employees in businesses in UK) |
Total turnover |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Food and Drink Retail |
1,517 |
863 |
169 |
13,304 |
15,853 |
Non-food retailers |
340 |
398 |
383 |
3,993 |
5,114 |
Retailers total |
1,857 |
1,261 |
552 |
17,297 |
20,967 |
Accommodation |
129 |
311 |
322 |
517 |
1,278 |
Food and drink services |
1,085 |
829 |
283 |
1,761 |
4,050 |
Out-of-Home total |
1,214 |
1,140 |
605 |
2,278 |
5,328 |
Total |
3,163 |
2,401 |
1,157 |
19,574 |
26,296 |
We do not have sufficient data on sales across shops by floor space to consider the potential impact of exemptions by the physical size of stores however the limited evidence available suggests that exempting retail stores below 2000 sq ft in Scotland does not present particular concerns in relation to total population health impact. Annex B uses the data on business sites by the number of employees at each site as a proxy for store size to consider the potential impact, including by SIMD and urban/rural status.
Modelling methods
The next subsections outline the high-level approach to modelling. It begins by describing the approach within each sector: retailers, out of home, manufacturers, government and health. The following section then presents the costs and benefits of each option, along with summaries of Net Present Values over the full policy appraisal period (25 years) of the options.
To estimate labour costs in the Retail and Out of Home sectors, we use job description data from the ASHE dataset and take the average (mean) 2022 hourly wage. All wage costs are up-rated by 30% to reflect non-wage labour costs such as overheads.
Retailers – food and non-food
These businesses include supermarkets and other grocery retailers, as well as non-food retailers. We model the costs as one-off costs (Familiarisation, Product Assessment, Store Planning & Implementation) and recurring costs (Profit reductions).
Familiarisation, product assessment, and store planning & implementation: We differentiate costs in these areas by business size (Micro, 0-9 employees; Small, 10-49 employees; Medium, 50-249 employees; Large, 250+ employees). The primary difference between the food and non-food retailers is the number of products we assume they need to assess, and the complexity of the process to do it.
Micro businesses are assumed to operate at the unit level and receive no back office support with their familiarisation. We therefore assume one shopkeeper per unit, needing time to familiarise themselves with regulations on volume promotion and placement restrictions, carrying out product assessment, and working with a sales assistant to plan and implement any changes to the store layout.
Small businesses are also assumed to have no back office support, however we assume that two managers per unit need to familiarise themselves with the regulations on promotion and placement restrictions. These same two managers then assess products. One manager then works with one retail assistant to plan and reorganise the store.
Medium sized businesses are likely to use more managerial support in understanding product regulations. We therefore assume 2 directors at enterprise level will distribute information to 2 workers per unit. For product assessment, we make assumptions on the ability of medium sized businesses to record product attributes using software. Therefore, we assume the need for director time, a set number of days programming time, stock assessments carried out by staff, and the time taken to disseminate this information to two managers per unit. We further assume that store planning is conducted at both enterprise and unit level, with managers at enterprise level distributing store plans to unit level.
Large businesses, due both to the scale of operations, make more use of enterprise (rather than unit level) staff to approach the policy. We therefore assume that in addition to director and purchasing manager time, programming time is also required in the familiarisation stage to prepare stock management software for updates on which products are restricted. We then assume some time is taken to distribute this information to a limited number of staff at unit level. At the product assessment stage, we include time spent by directors, programmers and stock checkers assessing products. We reduce the time taken to assess a given product as large retailers are likely to already store product nutrition information in their databases so can more quickly flag products that are restricted. This information is then distributed to a small number of staff members per store. For store planning and implementation, we again assume that the majority of work is carried out at enterprise level and then distributed to units.
We assume that there are no capital costs involved with reorganisation as the process is primarily around moving different products into the locations currently occupied by restricted products, rather than having to make physical changes to the locations themselves. Business engagement has highlighted potential costs involved in reconfiguration of store layouts, although the extent to which this would go beyond resource costs (i.e. capital costs of new shelving etc) is unclear. Business are encouraged to provide evidence to support costs associated with store reconfiguration resulting from location restrictions.
These transition costs resource assumptions are summarised in the tables below.
Retailers Transition Costs – Price Promotions
Familiarisation
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Retail – Food and non-food |
Micro |
No back office process. 90 mins of time for 1 shopkeeper at unit level |
Small |
No back office process. 90 mins of time for 2 shopkeepers at unit level. |
|
Medium |
Back office of 2 directors, distributing info to 2 sales assistants per unit. 90 mins of time for 2 directors at enterprise level, 45 mins of time for 2 sales assistants at unit level. |
|
Large |
Back office of half day of directors time, 2 hours of time for 3 purchasing managers, 1 day of programming for two programmers, distributing info to 2 sales assistants per unit with 45 mins of time each. |
Product assessment
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Retail – Food and non-food |
Micro |
No back office process, cost at unit level. 5 mins per product, assessed by shopkeeper with no computer system. 500 SKUs (individuals products) as mid-point. |
Small |
No back office process, cost at unit level. 5 mins per product, assessed by shopkeeper with no computer system. 500 SKU (individuals products) as mid-point for food, 200 SKU for non-food. |
|
Medium |
Back office of 1 director (half-day), distributing info to 2 sales assistants per unit (1 hour each). 2 stock control clerks checking at enterprise level, 3 mins per product. 5 Days of programming time for food retail, no programming in non-food due to small number of products. 1000 SKUs (individual products) as mid-point for food, 200 SKU for non-food. |
|
Large |
Back office of 2 directors (half-day), distributing info to 2 sales assistants per unit (1 hour each). 2 stock control clerks checking at enterprise level, 2 mins per product. 10 Days of programming time – pre-existing system with full nutritional information which needs development for regulations for food retail, no programming in non-food due to small number of products. 1700 SKUs (individual products) as mid-point for food, 200 SKU for non-food. |
Retailers Transition Costs - Location promotions
Familiarisation costs
Familiarisation costs for retail location promotion restrictions are assumed to be equal (but additional) to those of price promotions, with the exception of programming costs for which there are none assumed.
Store planning and implantation costs
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Retail – Food and non-food |
Micro |
No back office process, cost at unit level. Full day of work for proprietor and 1 cashier. |
Small |
No back office process, cost at unit level. Full day of work for proprietor and 1 cashier. |
|
Medium |
Back office of 1 manager at enterprise level, 4 days of work. Half day of work for one manager and 1 cashier at unit level. |
|
Large |
Back office of 1 manager at enterprise level, 4 days of work. Half day of work for 1 manager and 2 cashiers at unit level. |
The one-off familiarisation costs are made up of the time taken for members of staff to acquaint themselves with the new regulations. The total cost for price and location promotion restrictions combined is shown in Table 16 for both food and non-food retailers. The same staff time requirements are used to estimate the costs for both price and location restrictions, with the exception of programmer costs which are excluded from location promotions.
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
|
Retail - Food |
335,631 |
71 |
503,447 |
106 |
667,608 |
141 |
Micro |
184,428 |
44 |
276,642 |
66 |
368,856 |
88 |
Small |
57,116 |
120 |
85,674 |
180 |
114,232 |
240 |
Medium |
10,315 |
295 |
15,472 |
442 |
20,630 |
589 |
Large |
83,772 |
3,351 |
125,659 |
5,026 |
163,890 |
6,556 |
Retail - Non food |
106,545 |
113 |
159,818 |
170 |
210,749 |
224 |
Micro |
34,880 |
44 |
52,320 |
66 |
69,760 |
88 |
Small |
12,644 |
126 |
18,966 |
190 |
25,288 |
253 |
Medium |
3,212 |
214 |
4,818 |
321 |
6,424 |
428 |
Large |
55,809 |
1,860 |
83,714 |
2,790 |
109,277 |
3,643 |
Retail - Total |
442,176 |
78 |
663,265 |
117 |
878,357 |
155 |
Overall costs are skewed towards micro and small businesses, reflecting that there are significantly more businesses in these size categories. However, costs are significantly higher for large business on average.
The one-off costs of product assessment are shown in Table 17. As the products under the regulations are the same for price and location restrictions, we estimate only one set of costs across both promotion restrictions.
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
|
Retail - Food |
3,056,355 |
646 |
4,928,835 |
1,042 |
6,844,755 |
1,447 |
Micro |
2,305,350 |
550 |
3,842,250 |
916 |
5,379,150 |
1,282 |
Small |
356,975 |
752 |
594,958 |
1,253 |
832,942 |
1,754 |
Medium |
90,418 |
2,583 |
115,473 |
3,299 |
140,443 |
4,013 |
Large |
303,612 |
12,144 |
376,154 |
15,046 |
492,220 |
19,689 |
Retail - Non food |
301,624 |
321 |
390,291 |
415 |
478,957 |
510 |
Micro |
218,000 |
276 |
290,667 |
368 |
363,333 |
460 |
Small |
39,513 |
395 |
52,683 |
527 |
65,854 |
659 |
Medium |
5,171 |
345 |
5,824 |
388 |
6,476 |
432 |
Large |
38,941 |
1,298 |
41,117 |
1,371 |
43,293 |
1,443 |
Retail - Total |
3,357,979 |
592 |
5,319,126 |
938 |
7,323,712 |
1,292 |
Product assessment costs are estimated to be significantly higher than familiarisation costs overall, reflecting the time required for retailers to consider each product they stock and whether it meets the criteria as a restricted product.
For food retailers, we assume that micro and small businesses will be required to assess between 300 and 700 products across the scenarios, while medium size businesses will assess between 600 and 1,400 products and large companies between 12,000 and 25,000 products.
While larger food retailers will stock a larger range of products and therefore have a higher product assessment cost on average, the overall costs again reflect the much larger share of micro and small businesses.
The lower product assessment costs for non-food retailers compared to food retailers, relative to familiarisation costs, reflects that on average they will have a smaller range of targeted products for sale and the time taken to assess the products will therefore be lower. We assume a range of between 150 and 250 products requiring assessment across all business sizes.
The restriction of location promotions will also require the one-off adjustment of store layouts as stock is moved to meet the regulations. Given the lack of information on potential capital costs involved, this again is estimated through staff time required to undertake the required tasks. See Table 18.
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
|
Retail - Food |
975,177 |
206 |
1,950,354 |
412 |
2,925,532 |
619 |
Micro |
615,888 |
147 |
1,231,776 |
294 |
1,847,664 |
440 |
Small |
95,368 |
201 |
190,736 |
402 |
286,104 |
602 |
Medium |
31,573 |
902 |
63,146 |
1,804 |
94,718 |
2,706 |
Large |
232,348 |
9,294 |
464,697 |
18,588 |
697,045 |
27,882 |
Retail - Non food |
271,636 |
289 |
543,271 |
578 |
814,907 |
867 |
Micro |
116,480 |
147 |
232,960 |
295 |
349,440 |
442 |
Small |
21,112 |
211 |
42,224 |
422 |
63,336 |
633 |
Medium |
11,784 |
786 |
23,568 |
1,571 |
35,352 |
2,357 |
Large |
122,260 |
4,075 |
244,519 |
8,151 |
366,779 |
12,226 |
Retail - Total |
1,246,813 |
220 |
2,493,626 |
440 |
3,740,438 |
660 |
Table 19 combines the familiarisation, product assessment and planning and implementation costs to present the overall transition costs for retail businesses. This is presented for both overall costs and on an average cost per business split by business size.
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
Total Costs |
Per Business |
|
Retail - Food |
4,367,163 |
923 |
7,382,636 |
1,561 |
10,437,895 |
2,207 |
Micro |
3,105,666 |
740 |
5,350,668 |
1,275 |
7,595,670 |
1,811 |
Small |
509,459 |
1,073 |
871,368 |
1,834 |
1,233,278 |
2,596 |
Medium |
132,305 |
3,780 |
194,091 |
5,545 |
255,791 |
7,308 |
Large |
619,733 |
24,789 |
966,509 |
38,660 |
1,353,156 |
54,126 |
Retail - Non food |
679,805 |
723 |
1,093,380 |
1,163 |
1,504,613 |
1,601 |
Micro |
369,360 |
468 |
575,947 |
729 |
782,533 |
991 |
Small |
73,269 |
733 |
113,873 |
1,139 |
154,478 |
1,545 |
Medium |
20,167 |
1,344 |
34,210 |
2,281 |
48,252 |
3,217 |
Large |
217,010 |
7,234 |
369,350 |
12,312 |
519,349 |
17,312 |
Retail - Total |
5,046,968 |
890 |
8,476,016 |
1,495 |
11,942,508 |
2,106 |
Retailers profit reductions - Price promotions
Expenditure change of targeted food groups from price promotions
The economic modelling carried out by the SRUC/University of Aberdeen models the change in expenditure by food categories as a result of the removal of promotions on discretionary goods[34]. These figures are presented per capita and using 2018 prices for take-home food and drink expenditure. The per capita figures are updated into 2022 prices using the latest available estimate of total take-home food and drink expenditure, £10.5 billion in 2022[35]. Using the latest estimate of Scotland’s population of 5.4 million[36] we can estimate the total fall in expenditure across the different take-home food categories. See Table 20.
2022 expenditure (£m) |
Impact of restricting price promotions on sales (£m) |
||
---|---|---|---|
Multi-buy |
All price promotions |
||
Take home confectionery |
£504.0 |
-£14.99 |
-£82.23 |
Biscuits |
£231.0 |
-£15.18 |
-£57.16 |
Take home savouries |
£304.5 |
-£15.97 |
-£42.58 |
Cakes, pastries and sugar morning goods |
£315.0 |
-£11.75 |
-£40.56 |
Total puddings and desserts |
£126.0 |
-£9.51 |
-£26.86 |
Take home sugary drinks |
£630.0 |
-£25.17 |
-£62.31 |
Edible ices and ice cream |
£115.5 |
-£10.80 |
-£32.89 |
The economic modelling undertaken by SRUC/University of Aberdeen for the Scottish Government was based on the removal of price promotions from discretionary foods. It did not model the impacts on removing promotions from the additional foods now under consideration, such as ready meals.
We have therefore had to estimate the potential impact on the additional foods under consideration based on other available information, but recognise it will be subject to greater uncertainties due to this.
Food category |
% spend on promotion (2022)[37] |
% spend on multibuy and Y for £X (2022) |
% of total grocery spend (2022) |
% NPM test fail[38] |
---|---|---|---|---|
Sweet biscuits |
26.7 |
2.1 |
2.2 |
99 |
Total confectionery |
29.5 |
3.9 |
4.8 |
99[39] |
Cakes & pastries + higher fat/sugar morning goods |
20.2 |
5 |
3 |
100 |
Crisps & savoury snacks |
30.7 |
4.7 |
2.9 |
95 |
Puddings & desserts |
27 |
4.9 |
1.2 |
66 |
Ice cream & edible ices (excl. frozen dairy desserts) |
40 |
7.6 |
1.1 |
98 |
Regular soft drinks (excl. water) |
32 |
9.2 |
6 |
78.3[40] |
Breakfast cereals |
30.1 |
8.5 |
1.4 |
59[41] |
Ready meals |
31.1 |
17.5 |
3.6 |
18 |
Yoghurt & fromage frais |
37.4 |
8.5 |
1.5 |
18 |
Pizza |
30.2 |
3.9 |
1.2 |
73 |
Roast and processed potatoes |
25.1 |
4.2 |
0.9 |
4 |
To estimate the change in expenditure on additional foods under consideration (i.e. ready meals, cereals, pizza, etc) we base it on the changes in discretionary food and the share of discretionary and additional foods which are sold via promotion. In more detail:
1. We calculate the average modelled change in expenditure on discretionary foods from the economic modelling (i.e. change as a share of the total expenditure for each category).
2. We then calculate the share of additional foods which are sold on promotion (average of ready meals, cereals, pizza and roast and processed potatoes sold under multi-buy and TPRs), which fail a NPM test.
3. Similarly, we calculate the average share of discretionary foods on promotion and fail a NPM test.
4. We then calculate the ratio of (2) and (3) above, and apply this to the average change in discretionary foods (from (1)), to give us the estimated percentage change in additional foods under multi-buy and all price promotions.
5. We then apply this figure to the estimated total expenditure on additional food categories to give us the estimated change resulting from the restrictions on promotions for multi-buys and all price promotions.
Impact of restricting price promotions (£m) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
2022 expenditure (£m) |
Multi-buy |
All price promotions |
|
Additional foods (i.e. ready meals) |
£903.0 |
£31.1 |
£56.8 |
Expenditure change in non-targeted food and drink as a result of price promotions restrictions (substitution)
Restricting price promotions will reduce spending on HFSS foods which fall under the regulations. However, we assume this will be accompanied by a substitution towards spending on other foods which are not targeted. In the SRUC economic modelling, the ratio of expenditure falls on discretionary foods to increases in other non-targeted foods is -1.064 to 0.973, or 91%. While this was modelling based on discretionary foods only, we assume this expenditure substitution ratio also holds for the additional foods.
Change in retailer profits from price promotion restrictions (recurring costs)
The net change in retail expenditure is estimated using the estimated reduction in expenditure on targeted foods netted against the gains in expenditure from substitution of non-targeted food, using the 91% substitution ratio. The change in annual retailer profits are then estimated using an assumed profit margin of 4% in the central scenario (2% in lower, 6% in upper). The results for discretionary foods only are shown in Table 23 for the case in which only multi-buy price promotions are restricted. These are recurring costs which are assumed to be incurred annually.
Change in profits |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Category |
Revenues |
Change in expenditure |
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
Biscuits |
231,000,000 |
(15,175,628) |
(303,513) |
(607,025) |
(910,538) |
Confectionery |
504,000,000 |
(14,991,595) |
(299,832) |
(599,664) |
(899,496) |
Cakes |
315,000,000 |
(11,745,171) |
(234,903) |
(469,807) |
(704,710) |
Savoury snacks |
304,500,000 |
(15,968,569) |
(319,371) |
(638,743) |
(958,114) |
Pudding |
126,000,000 |
(9,506,134) |
(190,123) |
(380,245) |
(570,368) |
Ice cream |
115,500,000 |
(10,800,945) |
(216,019) |
(432,038) |
(648,057) |
Soft drinks |
630,000,000 |
(25,172,048) |
(503,441) |
(1,006,882) |
(1,510,323) |
Total targeted products |
2,226,000,000 |
(103,360,090) |
(2,067,202) |
(4,134,404) |
(6,201,605) |
Gains from substitution |
94,520,083 |
1,890,402 |
3,780,803 |
5,671,205 |
|
Profit net change |
(8,840,008) |
(176,800) |
(353,600) |
(530,400) |
Including additional foods such as ready meals in the price promotion (multi-buy only) regulations increases the estimated decrease in annual retail profits, but not by the same share as expenditure on additional products due to the lower share of these products failing NPM test. See Table 24.
Change in profits |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Category |
Revenues |
Change in expenditure |
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
Biscuits |
231,000,000 |
(15,175,628) |
(303,513) |
(607,025) |
(910,538) |
Confectionery |
504,000,000 |
(14,991,595) |
(299,832) |
(599,664) |
(899,496) |
Cakes |
315,000,000 |
(11,745,171) |
(234,903) |
(469,807) |
(704,710) |
Savoury snacks |
304,500,000 |
(15,968,569) |
(319,371) |
(638,743) |
(958,114) |
Pudding |
126,000,000 |
(9,506,134) |
(190,123) |
(380,245) |
(570,368) |
Ice cream |
115,500,000 |
(10,800,945) |
(216,019) |
(432,038) |
(648,057) |
Soft drinks |
630,000,000 |
(25,172,048) |
(503,441) |
(1,006,882) |
(1,510,323) |
Additional foods (i.e. ready meals) |
903,000,000 |
(31,067,547) |
(621,351) |
(1,242,702) |
(1,864,053) |
Total targeted products |
3,129,000,000 |
(134,427,637) |
(2,688,553) |
(5,377,105) |
(8,065,658) |
Gains from substitution |
122,930,537 |
2,458,611 |
4,917,221 |
7,375,832 |
|
Profit net change |
(11,497,101) |
(229,942) |
(459,884) |
(689,826) |
Extending the price promotion restrictions to cover all price promotions (e.g. Temporary Price Reductions) leads to a significant increase in estimated annual lost profits to retailers. See Table 25.
Change in profits |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Category |
Revenues |
Change in expenditure |
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
Biscuits |
231,000,000 |
(57,162,180) |
(1,143,244) |
(2,286,487) |
(3,429,731) |
Confectionery |
504,000,000 |
(82,226,909) |
(1,644,538) |
(3,289,076) |
(4,933,615) |
Cakes |
315,000,000 |
(40,557,855) |
(811,157) |
(1,622,314) |
(2,433,471) |
Savoury snacks |
304,500,000 |
(42,578,660) |
(851,573) |
(1,703,146) |
(2,554,720) |
Pudding |
126,000,000 |
(26,856,150) |
(537,123) |
(1,074,246) |
(1,611,369) |
Ice cream |
115,500,000 |
(32,894,981) |
(657,900) |
(1,315,799) |
(1,973,699) |
Soft drinks |
630,000,000 |
(62,310,881) |
(1,246,218) |
(2,492,435) |
(3,738,653) |
Ready meals |
903,000,000 |
(56,786,860) |
(1,135,737) |
(2,271,474) |
(3,407,212) |
Total targeted products |
3,129,000,000 |
(401,374,476) |
(8,027,490) |
(16,054,979) |
(24,082,469) |
Gains from substitution |
367,046,396 |
7,340,928 |
14,681,856 |
22,022,784 |
|
Profit net change |
(34,328,080) |
(686,562) |
(1,373,123) |
(2,059,685) |
Retailers profit reductions - Location promotions
Lastly, we estimate the change in sales from location promotions by assigning targeted products categories to those that are sold from either i) checkouts, ii) the end-of-aisle, iii) both. The share of sales which are currently via checkout locations is assumed to be 7.1%, and 20% of sales are assumed to come from other promotional locations.[42] The estimates for aisle promotion locations are used as a proxy for all non-checkout locations, such as display bins and store entrances for which there is limited specific estimates.
Promotion location |
||
---|---|---|
Category |
Aisle: front / end |
Checkout |
Biscuits |
Yes |
No |
Confectionery |
Yes |
Yes |
Cakes |
Yes |
Yes |
Savoury snack |
Yes |
Yes |
Pudding |
Yes |
No |
Ice cream |
Yes |
Yes |
Soft drinks |
Yes |
No |
Ready meals |
Yes |
No |
For checkout promotions, a number of large retailers have committed to voluntary restrictions on the placement of HFSS foods at checkouts. This is estimated to be 15.7% of total potential checkout sales of HFSS foods based on a search of public statements from retailers on voluntary actions and their accompanying market share (of all groceries). To note, this was carried out prior to restrictions on location promotions being implemented in England, and as such the figure may have increased if shops complying with English regulations apply any updated placement strategies to all UK stores.
Applying these estimates to the total expenditure on each food category provides an estimate of the total revenue of products in scope (i.e. sales from checkout or aisle locations not already voluntary restricted). See Table 28 for total estimated value of products in scope of location restrictions.
An assessment is then made of the impact on retail sales and profits of moving restricted products out of targeted locations, and them being replaced by non-targeted products. There are a number of studies which examine the impact of product location on sales[43][44][45]. These studies follow different methodology, food types and geography, and as such arrive at a range of results on the impact of location. We use this range of results to estimate the potential impact of location restrictions on sales uplifts across our different scenarios. See Table 27.
Store Location |
Estimated sales uplift |
||
---|---|---|---|
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
|
Aisle: Front / end |
20% |
30% |
53% |
Checkout |
0% |
18% |
25% |
Profit margins of 2%, 4%, and 6% are assumed for the lower, central and upper scenarios respectively. This is assumed to be the same across all types of foods and location placement. As discussed in the UK Government impact assessment on location promotion restrictions[46], it may be the case that profit margins are higher for confectionary products etc. However, to avoid potential double counting our approach is restricted to considering the total lost uplift in sales, with the overall impact factoring in the substitution to non-HFSS products which move into the restricted locations.
The total estimated reduction on annual retailer profits is shown in Table 28. This is split between discretionary foods only, and also discretionary and additional foods, as well as estimating the impacts of exempting businesses with less than 50 employees.
Foods in Scope |
Description |
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
---|---|---|---|---|
Discretionary only |
Products in scope |
417,211,788 |
417,211,788 |
417,211,788 |
Lost uplift |
67,385,500 |
95,270,612 |
142,635,895 |
|
Net of compensatory behaviour |
5,763,234 |
8,148,144 |
12,199,123 |
|
Lost profit |
115,265 |
325,926 |
731,947 |
|
Lost profit (micro/small exempt) |
98,124 |
271,756 |
611,887 |
|
Discretionary + additional |
Products in scope |
479,338,188 |
479,338,188 |
479,338,188 |
Lost uplift |
77,739,900 |
109,607,473 |
164,156,805 |
|
Net of compensatory behaviour |
6,648,807 |
9,374,323 |
14,039,727 |
|
Lost profit |
132,976 |
374,973 |
842,384 |
|
Lost profit (micro/small exempt) |
113,201 |
313,509 |
705,900 |
Out of Home Sector
The Out of Home (OoH) sector comprises restaurants, takeaways, event catering, pubs and hotels. We assume the structure of costs is similar to those incurred by retailers. We therefore separate costs into familiarisation, product assessment, store planning and adjustment, and reductions in profits.
We again separate the one-off implementation costs by business size. Micro and small businesses only incur costs at the unit level; medium and large businesses incur some costs at unit level, but also have costs at enterprise level.
For familiarisation, we expect micro businesses to need one owner taking between 1 and 2 hours to understand the new regulations on volume/price promotions, and a further 1 to 2 hours to familiarise themselves with location restrictions. Due to a lower number of products to assess at the smaller businesses, it will take around 1 to 3 hours to assess products.
At medium businesses, we assume it takes two directors at enterprise level between one and two hours to familiarise themselves with volume/price promotion regulations, then between half an hour and an hour to disseminate the information to two managers at each unit. This is repeated for location regulations. We only expect products to be assessed at the unit level, using the time of a manager.
Large businesses need time for purchasing managers, and general managers to understand both the volume/price and location regulations and time to disseminate the information. Again, product assessment is carried out at unit level.
These transition costs resource assumptions are summarised in the tables below.
Out of Home Transition Costs - Price promotions
Familiarisation costs
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Out of home |
Micro |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 90 mins. |
Small |
No back office process, cost at unit level. 2 Managers for 90 mins each. |
|
Medium |
Back office of 2 directors (90 mins each), distributing information to 2 managers per unit (2 hours each). |
|
Large |
Back office of 1 director (half-day), and 3 managers (2 hours each) at enterprise level. 2 Managers per unit (2 hours each) |
Product assessment costs
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Out of home |
Micro |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 100 mins |
Small |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 100 mins |
|
Medium |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 100 mins |
|
Large |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 150 mins |
Out of Home Transition Costs - Location promotions
Familiarisation costs
Familiarisation costs for OoH location promotion restrictions are assumed to be equal (but additional) to those of price promotions.
Product assessment costs
Product assessment costs are only required once, and cost estimates have already been calculated for price promotions. These will not need to be duplicated if both price and location restrictions are in place as product assessment is only required once.
Store planning and adjustment
Store Type |
Enterprise Size |
Resource Assumptions |
---|---|---|
Out-of-home |
Micro |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 1 day. |
Small |
No back office process, cost at unit level. One manager for 1 day, shop assistant for half a day. |
|
Medium |
Back office process of one managers for 2 days, at enterprise level. One manager for 1 day, shop assistant for half a day at unit level. |
|
Large |
Back office process of one managers for 2 days, at enterprise level. One manager for 1 day, shop assistant for half a day at unit level. |
We are not aware of any comprehensive data on the scale and impact of price and volume promotions in the OoH sector in Scotland which would allow us to produce robust estimates of the potential reduction in sales and profits from the introduction of such promotion restrictions. This is in line with the UK Government Impact Assessment, which was unable to cost the impact of restricting volume promotions on the OoH sector.
To estimate reductions in profits in this sector, we therefore only estimate the losses from the location restrictions. The lost profits from location restrictions are estimated from UK-level data for illustrative purposes. We take the estimated OoH market value from Kantar, and apply the proportion of sales through checkouts and other restricted locations in retail environments. We then define what proportions of sales are from shops in scope, and apply a profit margin to estimate lost profits. Lastly we assume that some lost sales are replaced by new (unrestricted) products in the same space, leading to some offsetting.
Location promotions restrictions in the OoH are expected to principally impact the food-to-go market. The analysis on potential reductions in OoH profits is therefore restricted to this segment of the market, which is estimated to be around 17% of the total OoH sector revenue. This is based on data provided by FSS on the share of OoH sales by channel in 2020, in which 17.2% of sales are estimated to be through bakery and sandwich shops and convenience, which we treat as the food-to-go section of the market for the purposes of this analysis.
The total size of the OoH market is estimated to be around £4 billion in 2022 prices. This is based on an estimate of £3.6 billion[47] uprated by the level of food inflation between 2021 and 2022 of 12.4%. The estimated size of the food-to-go market is therefore just under £700 million (i.e. 17% of the total OoH).
Estimates of the reduction in profit are based on assumptions that HFSS products sold in the OoH sector have a larger profit margin than non-restricted foods (31.5%[48] compared to 12.4%), and that currently all sales in locations within the scope of the restrictions (7.1% of sales based on checkout assumption) are comprised of HFSS foods. It is also assumed that after HFSS goods are relocated to non-restricted areas, 30% of their original sales are retained as per the UK Government impact assessment.[49]
The share of food sales within scope of the restrictions is adjusted by the percentage of products by value which would be included within the restrictions (i.e. 17% discretionary foods, raising to 25% when including additional foods such as ready meals), and by the share of turnover from exempt businesses (businesses with less than 50 employees) of 42% for relevant options.
The estimated net decrease in profits for the OoH sector (for central scenario) from the location promotion restrictions is shown in Table 32. These are assumed to be recurring annual costs.
Discretionary foods only |
Discretionary plus additional foods |
Discretionary plus additional foods with exemption for micro/small businesses |
|
---|---|---|---|
Checkout sales of HFSS food (£) |
6,303,607 |
7,680,544 |
4,418,891 |
HFSS profit margin |
31.5% |
31.5% |
31.5% |
Potential lost profits (£) |
1,985,636 |
2,419,371 |
1,391,951 |
Non-HFSS profit margin |
12.4% |
12.4% |
12.4% |
Profit from substitutes (£) |
781,647 |
952,387 |
547,942 |
Net loss after substitution (£) |
1,203,989 |
1,466,984 |
844,008 |
Retained sales from HFSS after reallocation |
30% |
30% |
30% |
Additional revenue from retained sales (£) |
1,891,082 |
2,304,163 |
1,325,667 |
Profit from retained HFSS (£) |
595,691 |
725,811 |
417,585 |
Lost profit from non-HFSS (£) |
234,494 |
285,716 |
164,383 |
Net additional profit after substitution (£) |
361,197 |
440,095 |
253,202 |
Net total lost profit (£), annual |
842,792 |
1,026,889 |
590,806 |
Manufacturing
To estimate the impact on Scottish manufacturers, we take estimated lost sales from retailers and OoH as a result of the promotion restriction as an input. By applying an assumed retailer mark-up to sales lost, we estimate lost sales to manufacturers. This is done separately for location and price promotion restrictions. We then assume a profit margin to manufacturers, and what proportion of manufacturer profits are retained in the UK.
It is assumed that there are no product reformulation costs from manufacturers. This is on the basis that manufacturers would only decide to undertake a reformulation if it was more profitable for them to do so than not. Therefore any costs in reformulation would be offset by increased profits – or in the context of this assessment lower recurring lost profits.
The central case estimates for the main combinations of restrictions is shown in Table 33 along with the key assumptions used around mark-up rates, profit margins, and profit retention.
Promotions |
Multi-buy + Location |
All price promotions[50] + Location |
||
---|---|---|---|---|
Targeted foods |
Discretionary |
Discretionary plus additional |
||
Change in sales in retail and OOH |
HFSS |
(203,043,227) |
(249,411,491) |
(516,358,330) |
Non-HFSS |
185,677,687 |
228,080,245 |
472,196,105 |
|
53% UK supermarket mark-up |
||||
Value of manufacturer sales |
HFSS |
(133,143,099) |
(163,548,519) |
(338,595,626) |
Non-HFSS |
109,838,125 |
135,813,785 |
295,889,758 |
|
6% Food and drink producers profit margin |
||||
Change in manufacturing profits |
HFSS |
(5,988,387) |
(7,505,694) |
(18,008,521) |
Non-HFSS |
5,125,841 |
6,459,597 |
16,064,155 |
|
49% of profits retained in Scotland |
||||
Manufacturer profits retained in Scotland |
HFSS |
(3,914,407) |
(4,808,326) |
(9,954,711) |
Non-HFSS |
2,511,662 |
3,165,203 |
7,871,436 |
|
Net change in manufacturer profits |
(1,402,745) |
(1,643,124) |
(2,083,275) |
Government Enforcement Costs
In line with the Verity House Agreement we continue to work with local government, FSS and enforcement professionals to help inform estimates and costing implication to local authorities Costing and funding scenarios will be kept under review and updated prior to publication of the final BRIA.
This section estimates the costs to local authorities in enforcing the regulations and providing support to businesses upon their introduction.
Enforcement scenarios
The potential cost will vary depending on the enforcement scenario used by local authorities. The modelling sets out potential costs under the three enforcement scenarios to present an illustrative range of costs which may be incurred by local authorities. These scenarios are:
- High resource/assurance – Verification and validation: This approach would assume that enforcement officers are visiting premises to verify that restrictions are being followed. In addition, it assumes that validation is being performed to ensure that non-HFSS status of products are being accurately calculated.
- Medium resource/assurance – Verification only: This approach assumes that enforcement officers are visiting premises to verify that restrictions are being followed however without the additional verification requirements of the option above. This option differs only in approach, not in locations visited or frequency of visits.
- Low resource/assurance – Verification only of high risk businesses (Reactive approach): This approach is consistent with the medium assurance approach with the difference being that inspections are not carried out as standard but based on the anticipated risk of non-compliance. We are assuming that only 5% of businesses fall into this category, and that longer inspection times would be required due to the greater perceived risk of non-compliance. This risk based approach is consistent with the principle to target enforcement where there is the most need.
Employment costs
The estimated costs are primarily based on estimates of additional time taken by staff to undertake the new responsibilities. This time is costed using data on hourly wages, uprated to reflect non-pay employment costs.
It is for Scottish local authorities to determine the most appropriate way to allocate resources to support the enforcement of regulations.
The average wages for both Trading Standard Officers (TSOs) and Environmental Health Officers (EHOs) is taken from ONS regional hourly wage data by occupation. As noted below, salary data provided on TSO wages by Scottish Local Authorities is significantly different from the ONS estimate for “Inspectors of standards”, the latter of which is therefore excluded from the analysis.
The most recent official regional wage data from the ONS at the required occupational level does not include figures for Scotland for 2022 for both TSOs and EHOs. 2021 figures have therefore been used and uprated into 2022 prices using Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the 12 months to June 2022 of 9%. Hourly wages are uprated by 30% to account for non-wage labour costs, giving an estimated hourly cost per TSO and EHO.
Region |
Description |
Code |
Median pay |
Mean pay |
---|---|---|---|---|
Scotland |
Environmental health professionals |
2483 |
20.56 |
22.05 |
Scotland |
Inspectors of standards and regulations |
3581 |
16.22 |
19.26 |
Uprated wage to account for non-wage labour costs |
Adjustment |
Median pay |
Mean pay |
|
Scotland |
Environmental health professionals |
30% |
26.73 |
28.67 |
Scotland |
Inspectors of standards and regulations |
30% |
21.09 |
25.04 |
Uprated by CPI to put into 2022 prices |
CPI* |
Median pay |
Mean pay |
|
Scotland |
Environmental health professionals |
9% |
29.24 |
31.36 |
Scotland |
Inspectors of standards and regulations |
9% |
23.07 |
27.39 |
*CPI 12 Months to June 2022
Members of the Financial Considerations and Delivery Group supporting the policy development provided the Scottish Government with results from surveys of salary information of EHO and TSOs across Scottish Local Authorities (LA):
- For EHOs in 2022, the mid-point wage from the local pay-scale was provided by 31 of the 32 Local Authorities. The mean hourly wage was £20.42 and the median hourly wage was £20.49.
- For TSOs, £21.86 was the average of the minimum and maximum salary points for 2022/23 salaries across 26 of the 32 Local Authorities supplying data.
For the purposes of this analysis the ONS pay figures have been used to allow consistency across different occupations in other elements of the assessment. Given the significant difference between the ONS figures for inspectors of standards and the salary ranges of TSOs we exclude the ONS figure from this analysis and use the higher hourly time cost of EHOs. We recognise in practice the deployment of resources will be a decision made by Local Authorities and could be a combination of different inspectors.
Familiarisation costs
There will be a cost to Local Authorities of familiarisation with the new regulations, training officers, the dissemination of guidance, and administration costs.
- Staff training/familiarisation with new requirements – It is estimated that there would be a slight reduction in training required should the low resource/assurance enforcement scenario be followed.
- Administration - supporting business implementation – It is anticipated that businesses may contact their relevant Local Authorities during the implementation period to these requirements coming into force for advice on how to implement restrictions.
- Administration - un-paid fines – where fines relating to offences for breach of these policies go unpaid, should the fines be over £200 in value then the Local Authority finance departments would make efforts to pursue payment. This is based on feedback from the Financial and Delivery Considerations Group.
- Other Administrative resource – this would include tasks such as responding to FOIs in relation to enforcement action, communications with businesses, and potential reporting in relation to enforcement action/levels of compliance.
We assume that the administration costs would be the same regardless of the enforcement scenario as the underlying requirements out with physical inspections should remain similar, and would be the equivalent of one FTE for one month per local authority. This is equivalent to 163 hours of work for each local authority.
The estimated training times per officer are based on feedback from Food Standards Scotland based on current enforcement regimes. These are assumed to equate to 2 hours per officer if employing a low resource/assurance enforcement scenario, rising to 5 hours per officer if employing a high or medium resource/assurance scenario. This is multiplied by the latest available estimate of the total number of EHOs of 202 as of November 2021[52]. It is assumed these costs would be the same regardless of exemptions to the policy by business or store size or type.
The time and cost estimates for this training and administration is shown in Table 35. These are assumed to be one-off costs incurred in the first year only.
Enforcement scenario |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Low Resource / Assurance |
Medium Resource / Assurance |
High Resource / Assurance |
||
Training |
Per officer |
2 |
5 |
5 |
Total hours |
404 |
1,010 |
1,010 |
|
Total cost |
£12,669 |
£31,673 |
£31,673 |
|
Administration |
Per LA |
163 |
163 |
163 |
Total hours |
5,216 |
5,216 |
5,216 |
|
Total cost |
£163,571 |
£163,571 |
£163,571 |
|
Total |
Hours |
5,620 |
6,226 |
6,226 |
Cost |
£176,240 |
£195,244 |
£195,244 |
Inspection frequency and additional time
Inspections of retail and OoH premises are already conducted through the standard operations of inspecting trading standards and environmental health. The additional cost of inspection in relation to the new regulations is therefore estimated as the additional time spent during each visit, rather than calculating the time and costs of an entire intervention including travel time etc.
This estimated time varies for the three different enforcement scenarios, given the different inspection requirements. The additional times are estimated to be separate for the inspection of both price and location promotion restrictions.
For example, if under the high resource / assurance enforcement scenarios it would require an additional 30 mins for each of price and location promotions restrictions to be added to existing inspections for the relevant locations to validate that requirements were being followed then additional resource should be calculated on this basis. Table 36 shows the additional time requirements across the enforcement scenarios.
Enforcement Scenario |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low Resource / Assurance |
Medium Resource / Assurance |
High Resource / Assurance |
|
Price |
1 |
0.25 |
0.5 |
Location |
1 |
0.25 |
0.5 |
In line with the UK Government impact assessments on HFSS promotion restrictions, the following assumptions are made regarding the frequency of inspections:
- Retail units are inspected once every 3.5 years
- Out-of-home units are inspected once every 2 years
The inspection rate is assumed to be 100% of eligible units for both the medium resource / assurance and high resource / assurance scenario. For the low resource /assurance scenario it is assumed that only 5% of premises would fall in the high-risk category of premises which would require inspection under this more targeted approach.
Number of business sites within scope of regulations
The number of business sites in Scotland - i.e. individual stores - which will potentially be within scope of the regulations and potentially subject to inspections is shown in
Table 37. This totals over 25,000 across retailers and out-of-home businesses. A breakdown is given of the split of business sites by the overall size of the business (number of employees in the UK) for the purposes of considering the impact of exempting businesses by size.
Description |
Number of business sites in Scotland (split by number of employees in businesses in UK) |
Total number of business sites |
|||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Micro (0-9) |
Small (10-49) |
Medium (50-249) |
Large (250+) |
||
Food and Drink Retail |
4,230 |
655 |
240 |
2,110 |
7,230 |
Non-food retailers |
800 |
145 |
80 |
1,050 |
2,080 |
Retailers total |
5,030 |
800 |
320 |
3,160 |
9,310 |
Accommodation |
850 |
650 |
205 |
275 |
1,980 |
Food and drink services |
9,045 |
2,490 |
365 |
2,105 |
14,010 |
Out-of-Home total |
9,895 |
3,140 |
570 |
2,380 |
15,990 |
Total |
14,920 |
3,945 |
890 |
5,540 |
25,300 |
Source: IDBR extract for relevant 5 digit SIC codes
Total annual inspection costs
Using the inspection rate and frequency of visits we can estimate the total number of units inspected annually under each of the enforcement scenarios. Applying the time per visit to this then allows us to estimate the potential annual inspections costs. These totals costs are shown in Table 38, Table 39, and Table 40 including the estimates if micro and small businesses (less than 50 employees) are exempt from the regulations (based on the total number of employees in the business).
Low Resource / Assurance |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Businesses within scope |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
|
Inspection rate |
5% |
5% |
||
Frequency of visits (per year) |
0.29 |
0.5 |
||
Time per visit, hours |
2 |
2 |
||
Units inspected annually |
All Businesses |
135 |
400 |
535 |
Micro/Small exempt |
50 |
74 |
124 |
|
Annual cost |
All Businesses |
£8,467 |
£25,072 |
£33,539 |
Micro/Small exempt |
£3,165 |
£4,626 |
£7,790 |
Medium Resource / Assurance |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Businesses within scope |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
|
Inspection rate |
100% |
100% |
||
Frequency of visits (per year) |
0.29 |
0.5 |
||
Time per visit, hours |
0.5 |
0.5 |
||
Units inspected annually |
All Businesses |
2,700 |
7,995 |
10,695 |
Micro/Small exempt |
1,009 |
1,475 |
2,484 |
|
Annual cost |
All Businesses |
£42,334 |
£125,360 |
£167,693 |
Micro/Small exempt |
£15,824 |
£23,128 |
£38,952 |
High Resource / Assurance |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Businesses within scope |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
|
Inspection rate |
100% |
100% |
||
Frequency of visits (per year) |
0.29 |
0.5 |
||
Time per visit, hours |
1 |
1 |
||
Units inspected annually |
All Businesses |
2,700 |
7,995 |
10,695 |
Micro/Small exempt |
1,009 |
1,475 |
2,484 |
|
Annual cost |
All Businesses |
£84,668 |
£250,719 |
£335,387 |
Micro/Small exempt |
£31,648 |
£46,255 |
£77,903 |
Reconfiguration support
In addition to the inspection costs, it is expected that there may be one-off costs in providing businesses with support on how to reconfigure premises and general advice on adhering to the new regulations.
It is challenging to estimate what level of resource may be required to perform this support. For the purposes of this analysis we have assumed that there would be a one-off cost in the first year to support with reconfiguration which is equal to the estimated annual inspection costs for each enforcement scenario. See Table 41.
Enforcement style |
|||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Low Resource / Assurance |
Medium Resource / Assurance |
High Resource / Assurance |
|||||||||
Businesses within scope |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
Retail |
OOH |
Total |
||
All |
8,467 |
25,072 |
33,539 |
42,334 |
125,360 |
167,693 |
84,668 |
250,719 |
335,387 |
||
Micro/Small exempt |
3,165 |
4,626 |
7,790 |
15,824 |
23,128 |
38,952 |
31,648 |
46,255 |
77,903 |
Annual overheads
While the expectation is that the new regulations will be encompassed into the standard inspection and enforcement regimes, there will likely be additional administration costs and general overheads associated with the responsibilities beyond the inspection time requirements. This would also include any additional time and travel costs for inspections and engagement. These would be ongoing annual costs going forward.
We have estimated these additional costs on the basis of a share of an FTE in each Local Authority. We have assumed that 5% of an FTE in each Local Authority would be required in the low resource / assurance enforcement scenario, and that overheads would be double that at 10% of an FTE in a medium resource / assurance and high resource / assurance enforcement scenario. Totalled across the 32 local authorities gives an estimate of the total FTE in Scotland, which is then multiplied by the EHO wage costs to give an annual estimate of overheads. See Table 42.
Enforcement scenario |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low resource / assurance |
Medium resource / assurance |
High resource / assurance |
|
Overhead (FTE) |
5% |
10% |
10% |
Total time (FTE) |
1.6 |
3.2 |
3.2 |
Total cost |
£82,789 |
£165,578 |
£165,578 |
Total enforcement costs
The estimated costs above are summarised in Table 43 to provide estimated total enforcement costs over the next 25 years. The annual costs are discounted using the recommend social discount rate of 3.5%.
The total estimated costs over the 25 year period with no exemptions range between £2.2 million and £9 million depending on the enforcement scenario. When exempting businesses with less than 50 employees, the estimated costs over the period range between £1.7 million and £4.4 million.
All businesses |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Low resource /assurance |
Medium resource /assurance |
High resource /assurance |
||
Year 0 (first year) |
Familiarisation |
£176,240 |
£195,244 |
£195,244 |
Inspections |
£33,539 |
£167,693 |
£335,387 |
|
Reconfiguration |
£33,539 |
£167,693 |
£335,387 |
|
Overheads |
£82,789 |
£165,578 |
£165,578 |
|
Total |
£326,107 |
£696,209 |
£1,031,596 |
|
Years 1-25 (next 24 years) |
Inspections (undiscounted) |
£804,928 |
£4,024,642 |
£8,049,284 |
Overheads (undiscounted) |
£1,986,939 |
£3,973,877 |
£3,973,877 |
|
Total (discounted) |
£1,868,034 |
£5,351,798 |
£8,044,681 |
|
Total over 25 years(discounted) |
£2,194,141 |
£6,048,008 |
£9,076,277 |
Micro/small exempt |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Low resource /assurance |
Medium resource /assurance |
High resource /assurance |
||
Year 0 (first year) |
Familiarisation |
£176,240 |
£195,244 |
£195,244 |
Inspections |
£7,790 |
£38,952 |
£77,903 |
|
Reconfiguration |
£7,790 |
£38,952 |
£77,903 |
|
Overheads |
£82,789 |
£165,578 |
£165,578 |
|
Total |
£274,610 |
£438,726 |
£516,629 |
|
Years 1-25 (next 24 years) |
Inspections (undiscounted) |
£186,968 |
£934,840 |
£1,869,679 |
Overheads (undiscounted) |
£1,986,939 |
£3,973,877 |
£3,973,877 |
|
Total (discounted) |
£1,454,558 |
£3,284,416 |
£3,909,916 |
|
Total over 25 years(discounted) |
£1,729,168 |
£3,723,141 |
£4,426,545 |
Guidance
Guidance will be prepared ahead of implementation that will provide advice on the recommended enforcement approach. It is uncertain what this will cost, and as such has not been included in the cost estimates at this stage. To give a general indication of the potential scale of costs, the Scottish Government budgeted funding of up to £50,000 for the preparation of materials to licence holders ahead of the introduction of Minimum Unit Pricing of Alcohol in Scotland[53].
Health
Section 2.3 sets out the health harms of poor diet and obesity as set out under the rationale for taking action.
Health benefits from the proposed policy are modelled using the Department of Health and Social Care Calorie model (v3). The model is calibrated to the English population although the results are adjusted for the size of the Scottish population.
This is a cohort-based Markov model that uses calorie reductions to estimate the benefits to health, and the associated changes in: NHS spending, Social Care spending, and Economic output. These are estimated over a 25 year horizon, and use different discount rates for health benefits compared to costs, in keeping with Green Book guidance. See Annex A for more details.
Input to the model is taken from the reduction in calories[54] estimated by the SRUC economic modelling work from the introduction of promotion restrictions[55]. The calorie reductions from the modelling work were produced for discretionary foods and for all price promotions and multi-buy promotions only.
The calorie reductions are adjusted for the other options in line with either the share of reduced targeted foods (i.e. share of sales which are discretionary to discretionary plus additional) and for exemptions by using the turnover of exempt businesses.
The model estimates the impact of reduced calories through the effect on the BMI distribution and therefore the incidence of type 2 diabetes, coronary heart disease, stroke, colorectal cancer, breast cancer and liver disease in the cohort. Mortality and incidence are age-adjusted.
Benefits from weight loss in the healthy and underweight BMI categories are also included to capture other benefits beyond the reductions in incidence of disease.
Health benefits to individuals are valued using Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs). QALY changes are calculated from the reduced number of deaths and the reduction of people living with the diseases. These are then converted into monetised QALYs using the value of a QALY given in the Green Book (currently £60,000).
People who fall ill with an obesity-related illness in later life may already be in less than perfect health. Accordingly, the model does not assume a QALY value of one for individuals in the “healthy” state (which in model terms means they are free of obesity-related illness). Instead, an age detriment is applied to all QALY values. This is done to allow for the increased prevalence of diseases not explicitly included in the model at older ages. The model uses a QALY disease detriment to calculate the QALY value for an individual in the disease state.
Savings to the NHS are calculated from the reduced treatment requirements for each disease.
Social care cost changes are calculated due to a reduced proportion of overweight, obese, and morbidly obese individuals and hence fewer people needing social care in the treatment scenario. This assumes that the probability of requiring social care increases with BMI.
Economic productivity effects are assessed in two categories. First, reductions in mortality are used to calculate the impact of mortality on economic output from an increased workforce. This is done by considering everyone within a cohort to earn the median wage of a person of that age and gender, with a larger workforce present in the treatment scenario.
Secondly, the model calculates the impact of morbidity on economic output using an employment rate that varies with disease state. This change has been made to reflect the lower productivity and rates of employment seen for individuals with one of the six modelled diseases (type 2 diabetes, coronary heart disease, stroke, colorectal cancer, breast cancer and liver disease).
The results from the baseline SRUC modelling inputted into the DHSC calorie model is shown in Table 45. These results are presented for the full policy appraisal period and have been uprated into 2022 prices.
Multi-buy only |
All price promotions |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
Lower |
Central |
Upper |
|
QALYs |
36,400 |
40,100 |
43,700 |
142,400 |
158,300 |
174,000 |
Economic Output (£m) |
235 |
258 |
281 |
914 |
1,016 |
1,117 |
NHS Costs (£m) |
153 |
169 |
185 |
603 |
670 |
737 |
QALY (£m) |
1,726 |
1,998 |
2,070 |
6,744 |
7,496 |
8,243 |
Social Care Costs (£m) |
189 |
207 |
225 |
706 |
780 |
853 |
Total (£m) |
2,303 |
2,632 |
2,761 |
8,967 |
9,962 |
10,950 |
The results from DHSC calorie model are provided in 2013 prices. These have been uprated into 2022 prices using the GDP deflators, with the exception of QALY value which have not been uprated as per guidance from DHSC.
The monetary value of the health benefits have been modelled based on the two key scenarios analysed in the SRUC economic modelling, all price promotions or multi-buy only price promotions and based on discretionary foods only. To consider the potential impacts across the wider range of options (i.e. including additional foods within the restrictions, exemptions based on business size), we weight these core results by the estimated reduction in retail profits in each option.
Summary of methodology section
To model the impacts of the policy propositions on Scotland, we have identified sectors affected: retailer, out of home, manufacturers, government, and health. We have identified how proposed regulations will affect costs, revenues and profits to businesses; the additional burden on local government; and the impacts on consumers’ health and spending in the health sector.
In order to address the uncertainty in this modelling exercise, we implement a range of values on some assumptions to present the estimate impacts under a lower and upper scenario alongside the central estimates.
Costs and Benefits of Options
The costs and benefits of all options are presented as a net present value (NPV) over 25 years (using a 3.5% discount rate), relative to the ‘do nothing’ option 1. The costs and benefits models were developed by separating affected sectors of the economy: Retail; Out of Home; Manufacturers; Health; and Government. The estimated costs are also broken down by one-off transition costs and also annual recurring costs, all in 2022 prices. The estimated benefits are not available as annual costs, and are presented in present value (positive) terms only.
Option 2
Building on two previous consultations undertaken by the Scottish Government in 2017/18, and in 2018/19, the 2022 consultation presented a number of different options for food categories to be targeted by promotion restrictions. Option 2 considers the implementation of restrictions on volume price promotions (i.e. multi-buy) and location restrictions for discretionary foods plus ice creams and dairy desserts only which fail a NPM test. This is on the basis that discretionary foods account for around 20% of calories and fat in our diet, and more than half of free sugars[56] intake. It includes no exemptions for any of the restrictions by store size, and as such all businesses are considered in scope for the assessment of costs and benefits.
Costs – Option 2
Option 2 Costs (£2022) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£962,433) |
(£2,540,756) |
(£5,327,555) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£176,800) |
(£353,600) |
(£530,400) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£115,265) |
(£325,926) |
(£731,947) |
OoH profits |
(£335,352) |
(£842,792) |
(£1,217,857) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£218,688) |
(£685,166) |
(£2,346,386) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£116,328) |
(£333,272) |
(£500,965) |
One-off transition costs |
(£7,793,029) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£19,460,195) |
Retail industry |
(£5,046,968) |
(£8,476,016) |
(£11,942,508) |
Familiarisation |
(£442,176) |
(£663,265) |
(£878,357) |
Product assessment |
(£3,357,979) |
(£5,319,126) |
(£7,323,712) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,246,813) |
(£2,493,626) |
(£3,740,438) |
OoH industry |
(£2,419,954) |
(£4,453,554) |
(£6,486,092) |
Familiarisation |
(£758,739) |
(£1,131,125) |
(£1,502,447) |
Product assessment |
(£256,337) |
(£512,674) |
(£769,011) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,404,878) |
(£2,809,756) |
(£4,214,634) |
Government |
(£326,107) |
(£696,209) |
(£1,031,596) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£23,439,062) |
(£54,930,225) |
(£106,068,944) |
Benefits – Option 2
We use the value of reduced profits in the retail and OoH sector to weight the estimated benefits from the DHSC calorie model outputs. Relative to the multi-buy only baseline (Option 3(a)), the reduction in profits are 81%, 82% and 82% from low, central, high scenarios respectively. Weighting the benefits by these shares gives an estimated present value of benefits of over £2 billion in the central scenario over the 25 year policy period. It should be noted that 76% of the benefits are from QALYs, which will not be financial savings but the monetary value on the improvement in peoples quality of living. See Table 47.
Low |
Central |
High |
|
---|---|---|---|
Economic Output PV |
£ 190,965,993 |
£ 210,917,471 |
£ 231,124,868 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 124,672,099 |
£ 138,290,229 |
£ 152,082,164 |
QALY PV |
£ 1,403,614,775 |
£ 1,633,731,156 |
£ 1,702,211,238 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 153,366,471 |
£ 169,131,935 |
£ 185,100,002 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 1,872,619,339 |
£ 2,152,070,790 |
£ 2,270,518,272 |
Summary – Option 2
Taking the present value of the costs and benefits together gives an estimate of the Net Present Value (NPV) of Option 2 over the next 25 years. See Table 48.
Low |
Central |
High |
|
---|---|---|---|
NPV (25 years) |
£ 1,849,180,277 |
£ 2,097,140,565 |
£ 2,164,449,328 |
Option 3
Option 3 would be consistent with categories set out in the UK Government regulations for England and considers the implementation of restrictions on volume price promotions (i.e. multi-buy) and location restrictions for discretionary foods and additional foods most associated with childhood obesity which fail a NPM test. In line with the UK Government approach, meal deals and TPRs are not included under this option. This is in line with Scotland’s aim to halve childhood obesity by 2030 and is in the context of the Scottish Health Survey 2022 that reported that one third of children were at risk of overweight (including obesity). This was 5 percentage points higher than in 2021, and the highest level since 2011.
We consider the potential impact of the policy with no exemptions (Option 3a), exempting micro and small businesses from location promotion restrictions (Option 3b) and exempting micro and small businesses from both location and price promotion restrictions (Option 3c).
Costs – Option 3
Option 3a (no exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£1,159,223) |
(£3,010,418) |
(£6,255,387) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£229,942) |
(£459,884) |
(£689,826) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£132,976) |
(£374,973) |
(£842,384) |
OoH profits |
(£408,605) |
(£1,026,889) |
(£1,483,881) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£271,372) |
(£815,401) |
(£2,738,331) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£116,328) |
(£333,272) |
(£500,965) |
One-off transition costs |
(£7,793,029) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£19,460,195) |
Retail industry |
(£5,046,968) |
(£8,476,016) |
(£11,942,508) |
Familiarisation |
(£442,176) |
(£663,265) |
(£878,357) |
Product assessment |
(£3,357,979) |
(£5,319,126) |
(£7,323,712) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,246,813) |
(£2,493,626) |
(£3,740,438) |
OoH industry |
(£2,419,954) |
(£4,453,554) |
(£6,486,092) |
Familiarisation |
(£758,739) |
(£1,131,125) |
(£1,502,447) |
Product assessment |
(£256,337) |
(£512,674) |
(£769,011) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,404,878) |
(£2,809,756) |
(£4,214,634) |
Government |
(£326,107) |
(£696,209) |
(£1,031,596) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£26,638,236) |
(£62,565,409) |
(£121,152,480) |
Option 3b (location exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£894,043) |
(£2,227,129) |
(£4,732,164) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£229,942) |
(£459,884) |
(£689,826) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£113,201) |
(£313,509) |
(£705,900) |
OOH profits |
(£235,085) |
(£590,806) |
(£853,730) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£229,130) |
(£677,876) |
(£2,278,178) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£86,684) |
(£185,054) |
(£204,530) |
One-off transition costs |
(£5,424,335) |
(£8,939,331) |
(£12,400,600) |
Retail industry |
(£4,053,586) |
(£6,561,519) |
(£9,106,896) |
Familiarisation |
(£297,642) |
(£446,464) |
(£589,289) |
Product assessment |
(£3,357,979) |
(£5,319,126) |
(£7,323,712) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£397,965) |
(£795,930) |
(£1,193,894) |
OOH industry |
(£1,100,034) |
(£1,958,562) |
(£2,816,027) |
Familiarisation |
(£469,045) |
(£696,583) |
(£923,059) |
Product assessment |
(£256,337) |
(£512,674) |
(£769,011) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£374,653) |
(£749,305) |
(£1,123,958) |
Government |
(£270,715) |
(£419,250) |
(£477,677) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£19,958,569) |
(£45,145,218) |
(£89,330,220) |
Option 3c (location and price exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£855,953) |
(£2,178,216) |
(£4,668,532) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£195,747) |
(£391,495) |
(£587,242) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£113,201) |
(£313,509) |
(£705,900) |
OOH profits |
(£235,085) |
(£590,806) |
(£853,730) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£229,130) |
(£677,876) |
(£2,278,178) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£82,789) |
(£204,530) |
(£243,482) |
One-off transition costs |
(£1,879,617) |
(£3,137,811) |
(£4,346,174) |
Retail industry |
(£989,214) |
(£1,564,159) |
(£2,176,548) |
Familiarisation |
(£153,108) |
(£229,663) |
(£300,221) |
Product assessment |
(£438,141) |
(£538,567) |
(£682,433) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£397,965) |
(£795,930) |
(£1,193,894) |
OOH industry |
(£615,793) |
(£1,134,926) |
(£1,652,996) |
Familiarisation |
(£179,351) |
(£262,042) |
(£343,670) |
Product assessment |
(£61,790) |
(£123,579) |
(£185,369) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£374,653) |
(£749,305) |
(£1,123,958) |
Government |
(£274,610) |
(£438,726) |
(£516,629) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£15,794,635) |
(£38,548,524) |
(£80,241,339) |
Benefits – Option 3
We use the value of reduced profits in the retail and OoH sector to weight the estimated benefits from the DHSC calorie model outputs. Relative to the multi-buy only baseline (option 3a =100%), the reduction in profits are 75%, 73% and 75% from low, central, high scenarios respectively for Option 3b and 71%, 70% and 71% from low, central, high scenarios respectively for Option 3c.
Option 3a (no exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 234,827,469 |
£ 257,945,199 |
£ 281,062,929 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 153,307,052 |
£ 169,124,446 |
£ 184,941,841 |
QALY PV |
£ 1,726,000,000 |
£ 1,998,000,000 |
£ 2,070,000,000 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 188,592,009 |
£ 206,842,848 |
£ 225,093,688 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 2,302,726,529 |
£ 2,631,912,493 |
£ 2,761,098,457 |
Option 3b (location exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 175,994,583 |
£ 189,010,024 |
£ 209,621,886 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 114,898,018 |
£ 123,926,384 |
£ 137,933,016 |
QALY PV |
£ 1,293,573,751 |
£ 1,464,039,763 |
£ 1,543,843,954 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 141,342,800 |
£ 151,564,642 |
£ 167,878,999 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 1,725,809,151 |
£ 1,928,540,812 |
£ 2,059,277,855 |
Option 3c (location and price exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 165,586,803 |
£ 179,534,674 |
£ 200,062,311 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 108,103,301 |
£ 117,713,772 |
£ 131,642,733 |
QALY PV |
£ 1,217,075,765 |
£ 1,390,645,305 |
£ 1,473,438,656 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 132,984,220 |
£ 143,966,484 |
£ 160,223,063 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 1,623,750,089 |
£ 1,831,860,236 |
£ 1,965,366,764 |
Summary – Option 3
NPV (25 years) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Option 3a (no exemption) |
£ 2,276,088,293 |
£ 2,569,347,084 |
£ 2,639,945,977 |
Option 3b (location exemption) |
£ 1,705,850,582 |
£ 1,883,395,594 |
£ 1,969,947,636 |
Option 3c (location and price exemption) |
£ 1,607,955,454 |
£ 1,793,311,712 |
£ 1,885,125,425 |
Option 4
Option 4 considers more extensive price promotions than those set out in the UK Government regulations for England and models the implementation of restrictions on all price promotions (i.e. multi-buy, meals deals and TPRs) and price and location promotion restrictions for discretionary foods and additional foods most associated with childhood obesity which fail a NPM test. This option is more aligned with the approach Welsh Government set out they are minded to pursue.
Economic modelling[57] has estimated that removal of price promotions such as temporary price reductions, multi-buy and 'Y for £X', just on discretionary foods such as cakes, biscuits, confectionary, crisps, etc., has the potential to reduce calorie intake by 613 calories per person per week (although it was noted this should be considered as an upper estimate). The impact is expected to be even greater if a wider range of high fat, sugar and salt food categories is included.
We consider the potential impact of the policy with no exemptions (Option 4a), exempting micro and small businesses from location promotion restrictions (Option 4b), and exempting micro and small businesses from both location and price promotion restrictions (Option 4c).
Costs – Option 4
Option 4a (no exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£1,944,878) |
(£4,363,809) |
(£8,205,322) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£686,562) |
(£1,373,123) |
(£2,059,685) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£132,976) |
(£374,973) |
(£842,384) |
OoH profits |
(£408,605) |
(£1,026,889) |
(£1,483,881) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£600,407) |
(£1,255,553) |
(£3,318,407) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£116,328) |
(£333,272) |
(£500,965) |
One-off transition costs |
(£7,793,029) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£19,460,195) |
Retail industry |
(£5,046,968) |
(£8,476,016) |
(£11,942,508) |
Familiarisation |
(£442,176) |
(£663,265) |
(£878,357) |
Product assessment |
(£3,357,979) |
(£5,319,126) |
(£7,323,712) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,246,813) |
(£2,493,626) |
(£3,740,438) |
OOH industry |
(£2,419,954) |
(£4,453,554) |
(£6,486,092) |
Familiarisation |
(£758,739) |
(£1,131,125) |
(£1,502,447) |
Product assessment |
(£256,337) |
(£512,674) |
(£769,011) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£1,404,878) |
(£2,809,756) |
(£4,214,634) |
Government |
(£326,107) |
(£696,209) |
(£1,031,596) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£39,410,424) |
(£84,567,145) |
(£152,852,089) |
Option 4b (location exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£1,704,337) |
(£3,613,481) |
(£6,725,539) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£686,562) |
(£1,373,123) |
(£2,059,685) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£113,201) |
(£313,509) |
(£705,900) |
OoH profits |
(£235,085) |
(£590,806) |
(£853,730) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£582,805) |
(£1,150,989) |
(£2,901,694) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£86,684) |
(£185,054) |
(£204,530) |
One-off transition costs |
(£5,424,335) |
(£8,939,331) |
(£12,400,600) |
Retail industry |
(£4,053,586) |
(£6,561,519) |
(£9,106,896) |
Familiarisation |
(£297,642) |
(£446,464) |
(£589,289) |
Product assessment |
(£3,357,979) |
(£5,319,126) |
(£7,323,712) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£397,965) |
(£795,930) |
(£1,193,894) |
OOH industry |
(£1,100,034) |
(£1,958,562) |
(£2,816,027) |
Familiarisation |
(£469,045) |
(£696,583) |
(£923,059) |
Product assessment |
(£256,337) |
(£512,674) |
(£769,011) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£374,653) |
(£749,305) |
(£1,123,958) |
Government |
(£270,715) |
(£419,250) |
(£477,677) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£33,131,328) |
(£67,682,799) |
(£121,736,019) |
Option 4c (location and price exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Recurring Costs (annual) |
(£1,348,619) |
(£3,330,344) |
(£6,328,492) |
Retail profits (volume/price) |
(£584,463) |
(£1,168,926) |
(£1,753,389) |
Retail profits (location) |
(£113,201) |
(£313,509) |
(£705,900) |
OoH profits |
(£235,085) |
(£590,806) |
(£853,730) |
Manufacturer profits |
(£333,080) |
(£1,052,572) |
(£2,771,991) |
Government enforcement costs |
(£82,789) |
(£204,530) |
(£243,482) |
One-off transition costs |
(£1,879,617) |
(£3,137,811) |
(£4,346,174) |
Retail industry |
(£989,214) |
(£1,564,159) |
(£2,176,548) |
Familiarisation |
(£153,108) |
(£229,663) |
(£300,221) |
Product assessment |
(£438,141) |
(£538,567) |
(£682,433) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£397,965) |
(£795,930) |
(£1,193,894) |
OOH industry |
(£615,793) |
(£1,134,926) |
(£1,652,996) |
Familiarisation |
(£179,351) |
(£262,042) |
(£343,670) |
Product assessment |
(£61,790) |
(£123,579) |
(£185,369) |
Store planning and adjustment |
(£374,653) |
(£749,305) |
(£1,123,958) |
Government |
(£274,610) |
(£438,726) |
(£516,629) |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
(£23,803,778) |
(£57,278,384) |
(£107,226,902) |
Benefits – Option 4
We use the value of reduced profits in the retail and OoH sector to weight the estimated benefits from the DHSC calorie model outputs. Relative to the all price promotions baseline (option 4a =100%), the reduction in profits are 84%, 82% and 83% from low, central, high scenarios respectively in Option 4b and 76%, 75% and 76% in Option 4c.
Option 4a (no exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 913,758,700 |
£ 1,015,963,401 |
£ 1,116,951,380 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 603,494,427 |
£ 670,414,172 |
£ 737,333,917 |
QALY PV |
£ 6,744,000,000 |
£ 7,496,000,000 |
£ 8,243,000,000 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 705,699,129 |
£ 779,919,210 |
£ 852,922,568 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 8,966,952,256 |
£ 9,962,296,783 |
£ 10,950,207,865 |
Option 4b (location exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 769,944,130 |
£ 833,804,150 |
£ 921,715,667 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 508,511,703 |
£ 550,210,882 |
£ 608,452,826 |
QALY PV |
£ 5,682,575,955 |
£ 6,151,989,235 |
£ 6,802,178,127 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 594,630,620 |
£ 640,081,988 |
£ 703,837,345 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 7,555,662,408 |
£ 8,176,086,255 |
£ 9,036,183,965 |
Option 4c (location and price exemption) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|
Economic Output PV |
£ 693,981,145 |
£ 759,044,584 |
£ 843,712,682 |
NHS Costs PV |
£ 458,341,741 |
£ 500,878,522 |
£ 556,960,659 |
QALY PV |
£ 5,121,930,813 |
£ 5,600,396,824 |
£ 6,226,523,161 |
Social Care Costs PV |
£ 535,964,133 |
£ 582,691,711 |
£ 644,272,974 |
Benefits PV (25 years) |
£ 6,810,217,832 |
£ 7,443,011,642 |
£ 8,271,469,476 |
Summary – Option 4
NPV (25 years) |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Low |
Central |
High |
|||
Option 4a (no exemption) |
£ 8,927,541,832 |
£ 9,877,729,638 |
£ 10,797,355,776 |
||
Option 4b (location exemption) |
£ 7,522,531,080 |
£ 8,108,403,456 |
£ 8,914,447,946 |
||
Option 4c (location and price exemption) |
£ 6,786,414,054 |
£ 7,385,733,258 |
£ 8,164,242,574 |
Summary of Costs and Benefits – All Options (Central)
Recurring Costs (annual) |
One-off transition costs |
Present Value of Costs (25 years) |
Benefits Present Value (25 years) |
Net Present Value (25 years) |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Option 2 |
(£2,540,756) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£54,930,225) |
£2,152,070,790 |
£2,097,140,565 |
Option 3a |
(£3,010,418) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£62,565,409) |
£2,631,912,493 |
£2,569,347,084 |
Option 3b |
(£2,227,129) |
(£8,939,331) |
(£45,145,218) |
£1,928,540,812 |
£1,883,395,594 |
Option 3c |
(£2,178,216) |
(£3,137,811) |
(£38,548,524) |
£1,831,860,236 |
£1,793,311,712 |
Option 4a |
(£4,363,809) |
(£13,625,779) |
(£84,567,145) |
£9,962,296,783 |
£9,877,729,638 |
Option 4b |
(£3,613,481) |
(£8,939,331) |
(£67,682,799) |
£8,176,086,255 |
£8,108,403,456 |
Option 4c |
(£3,330,344) |
(£3,137,811) |
(£57,278,384) |
£7,443,011,642 |
£7,385,733,258 |
Contact
Email: dietpolicy@gov.scot
There is a problem
Thanks for your feedback